PaanLuel Wël Media Ltd – South Sudan

"We the willing, led by the unknowing, are doing the impossible for the ungrateful. We have done so much, with so little, for so long, we are now qualified to do anything, with nothing" By Konstantin Josef Jireček, a Czech historian, diplomat and slavist.

Viable Solution to Hyperinflation in the Republic of South Sudan

By Baak Chan Yak Deng, Kampala, Uganda

salary
salary

salary in rss
Salaries in dramatic decline

March 4, 2017 (SSB) — As I said on Thursday Article that South Sudan economy has faces twin challenges of high inflation and low growth. Most of the short term policy instruments at our disposal trade off one for the other. For example, the some individuals have raised interest rates to combat inflation. This may lower inflation, but hurts growth because it increases the cost of funds for companies.

Yes it has long been considered a scourge, an obstacle to investment and a tax on the thrifty. It seems strange, then, that inflation is now touted as a solution to the rich world’s economic troubles. At first sight the case seems compelling. If central banks had a higher target for inflation, that would allow for bigger cuts in real interest rates in a recession.

Faster inflation makes it easier to restore cost-competitiveness in depressed industries and regions. And it would help reduce the private and public debt burdens that weigh on the rich world’s economies. In practice, however, allowing prices to rise more quickly has costs as well as benefits.

The orthodoxy on inflation is certainly shifting. A recent IMF paper co-authored by the fund’s chief economist suggests that very low inflation may do more harm than good. Empirical research is far clearer about the harmful effects on output once inflation is in double digits. So a 40% inflation target might be better than a goal of 20% as it would allow for monetary policy to respond more aggressively to economic “shocks”.

If the expected inflation rate rose by a notch or two, wages and interest rates would shift up to match it. The higher rates required in normal times would create the space for bigger cuts during slumps.

That argument is often bundled with another: that higher inflation greases the wheels of the economy. Wages should ideally be tied to productivity, but workers are usually reluctant to suffer the pay cuts that are sometimes required to maintain that link. A higher inflation rate can make it easier for relative wages to adjust.

A cut in real wages is easier to disguise with inflation of 30-40% than a rate of 10-20%. If the Central Bank  of South Sudan (CBSS) had a higher inflation target, say, then Sudan, Ethiopia, Kenya and Uganda would be able to regain competitiveness more quickly while avoiding unpopular cuts in nominal wages.

The anxiety about indebtedness makes inflation seem all the more appealing. Spending in rich countries, such as America and Britain, will flounder as long as households look to pay down the debts they acquired to buy expensive homes. A burst of inflation would speed up this process by eroding the real value of mortgages.

Inflation would work the same magic on government debt. It could also give a fillip to revenues. Tax allowances and thresholds are not perfectly indexed and inflation pushes taxpayers into higher income brackets where they face heftier tax rates.

In principle a modest dose of controlled inflation might work wonders. In practice, however, it may be hard to achieve and the benefits may not be quite as obvious. Take public debt. Inflation certainly helped reduce South Sudan’s government-debt burden after the Second War and conflicts, but far more of the shrinkage came from strong GDP growth and primary budget surpluses.

I suggested that less than a quarter of the reduction in South Sudan’s debt-to-GDP ratio between 2005 and 2016 came from negative real rates of return on government bonds.

The Hall-Sargent calculations show that almost all of this inflation tax was borne by those who held bonds with a maturity of five years or more. (That is because investors in short-term bonds could more quickly demand higher interest rates to compensate for inflation.) The trick is harder to repeat today. The average maturity of federal debt was more than seven years in the 1940s.

According to Bloomberg, the weighted average maturity of all South of Sudanese‘s public debt is now around five years. Using inflation to stiff investors’ works best when the bulk of borrowing is in the past: governments have an incentive to keep inflation (and thus bond yields) low as long as they are issuing fresh bonds to cover their huge budget deficits.

Another obstacle to higher inflation is that rich countries have promised themselves price stability. A central bank could not credibly commit itself to a 40% inflation target having broken a pledge to keep inflation close to 20%. Bond investors would demand an interest-rate premium for bearing the risks of a future increase in the target, as well as an extra reward for enduring more variable returns (higher inflation tends to be more volatile).

Moreover, many social-security and health-care entitlements are indexed to prices, as is a chunk of public debt, so higher inflation would drive up public spending.

For the private sector, too, inflation would be a mixed blessing. Take Britain, which might seem a likely candidate for inflation: its government sets the central bank’s inflation target and it has issued lots of long-term bonds. Alongside a rapid build-up of debt by some households there has been an increase in cash deposits by others.

Using inflation to transfer wealth from savers to debtors may help boost spending. But there are limits to how much you can do this in a country such as Britain, where both saving and mortgages are linked to short-term interest rates. Inflation would over time reduce the real burden of debt but would raise interest costs more quickly. Nor would it be politically popular: savers tend to be older and the old vote more often.

A burst of unanticipated inflation that was not expected to last would be a salve to the most troubled rich economies, but it is not something that can be easily engineered. Even so, how much regret would even the most hawkish central banker feel if inflation rose above 2% for a while without making bond investors nervous? The best policy may well be to talk tough about inflation while keeping interest rates low for as long as possible.

The author, Baak Chan Yak Deng, is a graduate in Bachelor of Science in Accounting and Finance at Star International University of South Sudan Affiliate to Busoga University of Uganda and can be reached at baak.maker44@gmail.com or 0954020202

The opinion expressed here is solely the view of the writer. The veracity of any claim made are the responsibility of the author, not PaanLuel Wël: South Sudanese Bloggers (SSB) website. If you want to submit an opinion article or news analysis, please email it to paanluel2011@gmail.com. SSB do reserve the right to edit material before publication. Please include your full name, email address and the country you are writing from.

About Post Author